By Saifedean Ammous
A glance at
Egypt’s public finances reveals a disturbing fact: The interest that the
country pays on its foreign loans is larger than its budget for education,
healthcare and housing combined. Indeed, these debt-service costs alone account
for 22 per cent of the Egyptian government’s total expenditures.
The
impact has become impossible to ignore. With growing political uncertainty and
a slowing economy, Egypt is likely to witness decreasing government revenues,
increasing demands for urgent spending, and rising interest rates on government
borrowing. This could lead to a fiscal catastrophe for the government at the
very moment when the country is attempting a complicated political transition.
Egypt’s public debt is around 80 per cent of the GDP, very close to the 90 per
cent level that economists Kenneth Rogoff and Carmen Reinhart identify as a
harbinger of slower growth and heightened vulnerability to financial and fiscal
crises. Egyptians need only glance north, at the European debt crisis, to
understand they should sort out their debt problem now, rather than waiting
until it reaches Greek proportions.
This
debt was incurred during the 30-year reign of the deposed president, Hosni
Mubarak. In international law, debt that is incurred without the consent of the
people, and that is not used to their benefit, is referred to as “odious”; as
such, it is not considered transferable to successor regimes. The reasoning is
simple and logical: if someone fraudulently borrows money in my name, I am not
expected to pay it back, and neither should a country’s population when an
unrepresentative leader borrows in their name and to their detriment.
For
three decades, Mubarak’s borrowing only enriched him and his ruling clique
while impoverishing and repressing the rest of Egypt. Corruption was rife, but
not just the covert type: public money was openly used to support many
businesses under flimsy pretexts like “fostering economic growth” and “creating
employment”. Along with regulatory capture, this harmed competitiveness, market
openness, and Egypt’s small and medium-sized businesses.
The
beneficiaries of this largesse are now mostly sitting in prison awaiting trial.
The rest of Egypt, however, only felt this money in the form of an
ever-expanding state apparatus that solidified Mubarak’s rule, crushed dissent,
and repressed millions. When Egyptians rose up against Mubarak in January, they
were confronted by weapons paid for with borrowed money.
Is
it fair to expect Egyptians to continue paying for their previous repression
and impoverishment at the hands of Mubarak and his cronies? Since this money
clearly benefited Mubarak but not his people, should it not be Mubarak, rather
than his victims, who is held responsible for it?
The
type of regime Mubarak was running had been clear for many years, and it was
also clear how the money was being used. A prudent lender should have
considered these facts before making the loans. So the banks and international
institutions that lent money to Mubarak should bear the responsibility of their
choice to bankroll his repressive regime.
The
new Egypt should make a clean break with Mubarak and his creditors, and let
them sort out their business among themselves without involving the Egyptian
people. The Egyptian government’s only role should be to help liquidate Mubarak
assets for repayment should the need arise.
This
would be not only fair, but it also would teach an important lesson to those
who bankroll dictators - a lesson that is likely to have an immediate positive
impact worldwide. Lenders to a repressive regime will no longer expect these
debts to be repaid by its successors, immediately making lenders worldwide
careful about lending to them.
An
Egyptian precedent would bring awareness and sobriety to an entire generation
of lenders that is not accustomed to considering this type of risk, and that
may even be unfamiliar with the doctrine of odious debt. Repressive regimes
would find it harder to borrow, which would, in turn, make it harder for them
to repress their people, and make it easier and cheaper for responsible and
legitimate governments to secure important funding when they need it.
Transferring liability for foreign debt to Mubarak should not have negative
economic consequences for Egypt in the long run. This move should not be
understood as a move towards fiscal recklessness, but as a one-time break from
it. With a smaller debt burden and interest payments, Egypt’s fiscal position
would improve significantly, and threats to economic growth would recede.
Foreign lenders’ resulting caution would prevent future Egyptian governments
from irresponsibly saddling their populace with debt.
Perhaps
most importantly, the days of borrowing to build a large state security
apparatus would be gone for good - worldwide. For the sake of Egyptians and
people living under tyranny everywhere, Egypt’s government must take a brave
stand.
-This commentary was published in The Jordan Times on 09/10/2011
-The writer is visiting scholar at the Centre for Capitalism and Society in Columbia University and lecturer in Economics at the Lebanese American University. ©Project Syndicate, 2011. www.project-syndicate.org
-The writer is visiting scholar at the Centre for Capitalism and Society in Columbia University and lecturer in Economics at the Lebanese American University. ©Project Syndicate, 2011. www.project-syndicate.org
No comments:
Post a Comment